Plurality Veto: A Simple Voting Rule Achieving Optimal Metric Distortion
- URL: http://arxiv.org/abs/2206.07098v2
- Date: Fri, 30 Jun 2023 00:54:21 GMT
- Title: Plurality Veto: A Simple Voting Rule Achieving Optimal Metric Distortion
- Authors: Fatih Erdem Kizilkaya and David Kempe
- Abstract summary: metric distortion framework posits n voters and m candidates are jointly embedded in a metric space.
A voting rule's purpose is to pick a candidate with minimum total distance to the voters, given only the rankings, but not the actual distances.
We show that a simple voting rule, called Plurality Veto, achieves the same optimal distortion of 3.
- Score: 11.282341369957212
- License: http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
- Abstract: The metric distortion framework posits that n voters and m candidates are
jointly embedded in a metric space such that voters rank candidates that are
closer to them higher. A voting rule's purpose is to pick a candidate with
minimum total distance to the voters, given only the rankings, but not the
actual distances. As a result, in the worst case, each deterministic rule picks
a candidate whose total distance is at least three times larger than that of an
optimal one, i.e., has distortion at least 3. A recent breakthrough result
showed that achieving this bound of 3 is possible; however, the proof is
non-constructive, and the voting rule itself is a complicated exhaustive
search.
Our main result is an extremely simple voting rule, called Plurality Veto,
which achieves the same optimal distortion of 3. Each candidate starts with a
score equal to his number of first-place votes. These scores are then gradually
decreased via an n-round veto process in which a candidate drops out when his
score reaches zero. One after the other, voters decrement the score of their
bottom choice among the standing candidates, and the last standing candidate
wins. We give a one-paragraph proof that this voting rule achieves distortion
3. This rule is also immensely practical, and it only makes two queries to each
voter, so it has low communication overhead.
We also generalize Plurality Veto into a class of randomized voting rules in
the following way: Plurality veto is run only for k < n rounds; then, a
candidate is chosen with probability proportional to his residual score. This
general rule interpolates between Random Dictatorship (for k=0) and Plurality
Veto (for k=n-1), and k controls the variance of the output. We show that for
all k, this rule has distortion at most 3.
Related papers
- 3+ Seat Risk-Limiting Audits for Single Transferable Vote Elections [56.12949230611067]
We present an assertion-based approach to conducting full or partial RLAs for STV elections with three or more seats.
We show that we can quite often form partial audits that verify most, and sometimes all, of the reported winners.
We evaluate our method on a dataset of over 500 three- and four-seat STV elections from the 2017 and 2022 local council elections in Scotland.
arXiv Detail & Related papers (2025-03-19T00:29:53Z) - Efficient Lower Bounding of Single Transferable Vote Election Margins [56.12949230611067]
Single transferable vote (STV) is a system of preferential proportional voting employed in multi-seat elections.
The margin of victory, or simply'margin', is the smallest number of ballots that need to be manipulated to alter the set of winners.
Lower bounds on the margin can also be used for this purpose, in cases where exact margins are difficult to compute.
arXiv Detail & Related papers (2025-01-24T13:39:23Z) - Optimal bounds for dissatisfaction in perpetual voting [84.02572742131521]
We consider a perpetual approval voting method that guarantees that no voter is dissatisfied too many times.
We identify a sufficient condition on voter behavior under which a sublinear growth of dissatisfaction is possible.
We present a voting method with sublinear guarantees on dissatisfaction under bounded conflicts, based on the standard techniques from prediction with expert advice.
arXiv Detail & Related papers (2024-12-20T19:58:55Z) - How many classifiers do we need? [50.69951049206484]
We provide a detailed analysis of how the disagreement and the polarization among classifiers relate to the performance gain achieved by aggregating individual classifiers.
We prove results for the behavior of the disagreement in terms of the number of classifiers.
Our theories and claims are supported by empirical results on several image classification tasks with various types of neural networks.
arXiv Detail & Related papers (2024-11-01T02:59:56Z) - NoVo: Norm Voting off Hallucinations with Attention Heads in Large Language Models [70.02816541347251]
This paper presents a lightweight method, Norm Voting (NoVo), which harnesses the untapped potential of attention head norms to enhance factual accuracy.
On TruthfulQA MC1, NoVo surpasses the current state-of-the-art and all previous methods by an astounding margin -- at least 19 accuracy points.
arXiv Detail & Related papers (2024-10-11T16:40:03Z) - Improving the Computational Efficiency of Adaptive Audits of IRV Elections [54.427049258408424]
AWAIRE can audit IRV contests with any number of candidates, but the original implementation incurred memory and computation costs that grew superexponentially with the number of candidates.
This paper improves the algorithmic implementation of AWAIRE in three ways that make it practical to audit IRV contests with 55 candidates, compared to the previous 6 candidates.
arXiv Detail & Related papers (2024-07-23T13:28:00Z) - Efficient Weighting Schemes for Auditing Instant-Runoff Voting Elections [57.67176250198289]
AWAIRE involves adaptively weighted averages of test statistics, essentially "learning" an effective set of hypotheses to test.
We explore schemes and settings more extensively, to identify and recommend efficient choices for practice.
A limitation of the current AWAIRE implementation is its restriction to a small number of candidates.
arXiv Detail & Related papers (2024-02-18T10:13:01Z) - Breaking the Metric Voting Distortion Barrier [10.143374372425757]
We consider the problem of metric distortion in social choice.
Finding a randomized rule that guarantees distortion $3 - epsilon$ has been a major challenge in computational social choice.
We give a rule that guarantees distortion less than $2.753$.
arXiv Detail & Related papers (2023-06-30T17:56:33Z) - Candidate Incentive Distributions: How voting methods shape electoral incentives [0.0]
We find that Instant Runoff Voting incentivizes candidates to appeal to a wider range of voters than Plurality Voting.
We find that Condorcet methods and STAR (Score Then Automatic Runoff) Voting provide the most balanced incentives.
arXiv Detail & Related papers (2023-06-12T14:32:46Z) - Accelerating Voting by Quantum Computation [35.03314687289671]
We propose a quantum-accelerated voting algorithm that can be applied to any anonymous voting rule.
Our algorithm outputs the correct winner with high probability in $Thetaleft(fracntextMOVright)$ time.
arXiv Detail & Related papers (2023-01-08T07:29:38Z) - Truth-tracking via Approval Voting: Size Matters [3.113227275600838]
We consider a simple setting where votes consist of approval ballots.
Each voter approves a set of alternatives which they believe can possibly be the ground truth.
We define several noise models that are approval voting variants of the Mallows model.
arXiv Detail & Related papers (2021-12-07T12:29:49Z) - Obvious Manipulability of Voting Rules [105.35249497503527]
The Gibbard-Satterthwaite theorem states that no unanimous and non-dictatorial voting rule is strategyproof.
We revisit voting rules and consider a weaker notion of strategyproofness called not obvious manipulability.
arXiv Detail & Related papers (2021-11-03T02:41:48Z) - The Complexity of Learning Approval-Based Multiwinner Voting Rules [9.071560867542647]
We study the learnability of multiwinner voting, focusing on the class of approval-based committee scoring (ABCS) rules.
Our goal is to learn a target rule (i.e., to learn the corresponding scoring function) using information about the winning committees of a small number of profiles.
We prove that deciding whether there exists some ABCS rule that makes a given committee winning in a given profile is a hard problem.
arXiv Detail & Related papers (2021-10-01T08:25:05Z) - Bribery as a Measure of Candidate Success: Complexity Results for
Approval-Based Multiwinner Rules [58.8640284079665]
We study the problem of bribery in multiwinner elections, for the case where the voters cast approval ballots (i.e., sets of candidates they approve)
We consider a number of approval-based multiwinner rules (AV, SAV, GAV, RAV, approval-based Chamberlin--Courant, and PAV)
In general, our problems tend to be easier when we limit out bribery actions on increasing the number of approvals of the candidate that we want to be in a winning committee.
arXiv Detail & Related papers (2021-04-19T08:26:40Z)
This list is automatically generated from the titles and abstracts of the papers in this site.
This site does not guarantee the quality of this site (including all information) and is not responsible for any consequences.